Once upon a time in the town of Crowville, somewhere deep in the
heartland of America, the town elders secured the imposition of a poll
tax to be paid by everyone in Crowville who votes in any political
election in that handsome burgh. The tax took the form of a flat $100
fee to be paid by every man and woman each time he or she seeks
admission to a polling place in Crowville.
The elders further arranged for the proceeds of this tax to be used
to subsidize transportation to the polls of low-income Crowvillians.
The elders heartily patted themselves on their backs for their wisdom
and charity. “This tax – er, really, a magnanimous benefit to
Crowville’s poor – will increase the political participation of poor
Crowvillians. The poor will now find voting to be less costly
as a result of this tax. The poor will therefore vote in larger numbers
than before – and, certainly, not in smaller numbers. Yeah for us!!”
A small cadre of skeptical Crowvillians frowned. These skeptics
(they thought of themselves as realists, so that is what we will call
them from here on in) asked the elders: “How do you figure that imposing
a tax on the act of voting will increase people’s
willingness to vote? Aren’t you worried that the monetary value to poor
Crowvillians of whatever transportation subsidy you supply will be far
less than the direct cost to each of them of the poll tax that they must
now pay in order to vote? Surely a Crowvillian who is too poor to buy a
bus ticket to a polling place, or who can’t find a friend to drive him
or her, will be very negatively affected by your poll tax. The final
result will be less, not more, voting.”
The elders snarled at the realists. “Don’t be so simple-minded, you
ideologues you. Yes, in simple textbook theory raising the cost of
voting with a poll tax discourages voting, especially of the poorest of
our citizens. But the real-world is much more complicated than your
basic theory. First, we’re recycling the bulk of the proceeds of the
tax into our ‘Transportation to the Polls” initiative. Second, it’s
really an empirical question of whether or not a poll tax in fact
discourages voting. One should not prejudge the matter based merely
upon theory. And you do realize, don’t you, that people’s demand to
vote is such that they are unlikely to be dissuaded from voting merely
by a extra monetary charge to do so?”
The realists’ jaws dropped. Never mind the obvious logical
inconsistency in the elders’ argument for why a poll tax is unlikely to
discourage voting. The realists were flabbergasted that the elders
really were confident that conditions affecting real-world voting were
such that their poll-tax scheme would not discourage voting.
The realists pointed out to Crowville’s elders that they – the
realists – actually have several empirical studies that show that poll
taxes do in fact, as common sense suggests, reduce people’s willingness
to vote. The elders snarled even more dismissively, insisting that
those empirical studies are naive and flawed.
The elders continued: “On our side are the best politimetricians in
the world. These quant-jocks have done serious empirical research into
the effects of poll taxes on voting and they conclude that, when the
models are properly specified and all the relevant real-world trends are
correctly accounted for, higher poll taxes do not reduce voting. To
deny these results is to deny Science. To deny these result is to
substitute ideology for fact. We elders have Science on our side! The
poll tax is supported by Science!”
The realists responded with more – and more elaborate – empirical
studies of their own. The realists’ studies found that, when the models
are properly specified and all the relevant real-world trends are
correctly accounted for, higher poll taxes do indeed reduce voting.
There ensued a duel of quantitative studies. This duel went on
endlessly; indeed, the duel continues down to this very day. (One of
the elders’ most popular studies is the study that found that while in
fact voting did decline in jurisdictions in which poll taxes were
raised, when controlling for the independent – ‘exogenous’ – trend of a
decline in voting in those jurisdictions, the higher poll taxes in fact
appear not to discourage voting at all.) Study after study, each one
more elaborate and technical and minutely specified than its
predecessor, poured forth.
Astonishingly (for it is, isn’t it, astonishing?) the elders’ studies
always found that poll taxes do not discourage voting while the
realists’ studies found that poll taxes do indeed discourage voting.
The elders, while they cannot be said to have won the scientific
argument, won the public-relations argument. The elders successfully
portrayed the poll tax as a way to help poor voters; the
elders’ intentions were oh-so-good and noble. The people sided
overwhelmingly with the elders, and the poll tax was raised (and,
indeed, indexed to inflation!). And all realists were ridiculed as
unfeeling knuckle-draggers when they pointed out that the empirical
record in favor of the poll tax is far too weak – and the logical
argument against it is far too strong – to justify a poll tax. The
elders’ self-professed morality and good intentions gave credence to
their dismissal of the realists’ concerns and to their assurances to the
people that science is clear that poll taxes do not discourage voting.
Reprinted in its entirety:
HT: Don
http://cafehayek.com/2015/09/a-tale.html
The Twenty-fourth Amendment (Amendment XXIV) of the United States Constitution prohibits both Congress and the states from conditioning the right to vote in federal elections on payment of a poll tax or other types of tax. The amendment was proposed by Congress to the states on August 27, 1962, and was ratified by the states on January 23, 1964.
ReplyDeleteSouthern states of the former Confederacy adopted poll taxes in laws of the late 19th century and new constitutions from 1890 to 1908, after the Democratic Party had generally regained control of state legislatures decades after the end of Reconstruction, as a measure to prevent African Americans and often poor whites from voting. Use of the poll taxes by states was held to be constitutional by the Supreme Court of the United States in the 1937 decision Breedlove v. Suttles.
Your history is spot on.. no disagreements from me... the economic parallels, the quantitative ‘evidence’ used to enforce them and the harms that they inflict, however, seem to have eluded you.
Delete